Bhattacharya, Sukumar;
The East India Company and the Economy of Bengal: From 1704 to 1740
Firma K. L. Mukhopadhyay, 1969, 232 pages
topics: | history | india | bengal | british-raj |
detailed descriptive history of the events after charnock establishes the calcutta offices of the company, during the Alivardi regime (ends before plassey).
The rebellion of Sobha Singh in 1696 secured for the Company the permission to fortify Calcutta, while the purchase of the zamindari of Calcutta, Sutinati and Govindpur in 1698 by the East India Company ensured to it a definite revenue which was regarded by Sir Josia Child as the 'foundation of power'. These events were followed in 1700 by the creation, by the Company, of Fort William as the seat of a Presidency, independent of Madras, with Sir Charles Eyre as its first President and Governor, and the amalgamation in 1702 of the "old" and "new" English Companies under the style and title of "The United Company of Merchants of England Trading to the East Indies". The union of the two Companies had been consummated by the award of Earl Godolphin in 1708-09. From this time onward there followed a progressive development of the East India Company's trade. Dividends were paid regularly at a rate fluctuating between 5 and 10 per cent. From 5 per cent in 1708-09 the dividend rose to 10 per cent in 1711-12, at which rate it continued till 1722, when it dropped to 8 per cent in 1743, at which figure it continued till 1755. The development of the Company's trade is also evident from the number and tonnage of ships despatched annually to the East. From an annual average of eleven ships of about 800 tons despatched for the five years from 1708-09 to 1711-13, the number rose to twenty-one ships of about 490 tons in the quinquennium from 1735 to 1740. While in 1708-09 out of ten ships despatched from Britain only four were bound for the 'Coast and Bay', that is, the eastern coast of India, in 1739-40 out of thirty-nine ships so despatched nineteen were bound for the eastern coasts, and of these nineteen ships no less than nine were specially earmarked for Bengal. The Union of the two Companies and the administration of the 'rotation government' from 1702 to 1709 coincided with a turning period in the history of Bengal. Four years before the final amalgamation of tbe two Companies under the award of 1708-09, Murshid Kuli Khan, the Diwan of Bengal, transferred his headquarters from Dacca to Murshidabad, which from 1704 became the centre of gravity in the financial administration of the province. The death of Aurangzib, in 1707, at once let loose the forces of disintegration, which gradually removed all elements of cohesion in the Moghul Empire. p.17 Gerald Aungier, who became President at Surat and Governor of Bombay in 1669, wrote a lengthy and striking despatch to the Directors in 1677, recommending: a severe and vigorous [policy to ensure the stability of the trade]. Justice and necessity of your estate now require that in violent distempers, violent cures are only successful; that the times now require you to manage your general commerce with your sword in your hands.
[the farman allowed the company the use of the mint at murshidabad, but...] Tbe use of the mint at Murshidabad was denied on the ground that the Nawab's chief mutasaddi (the officer who operated it), was dangerously ill and nothing could be determined in this regard till he recovered or was dead. [Consultations, 18 July and 50 July 1717.] An attempt to gain this and certain other privileges in 1724, even on the offer of paying Rs 40,000 to the Nawab, met with little success.] [this was primarily because the royal bankers, jagat seth & co, felt that they would lose their monopoly on the mint]
English traders came to India early in the seventeenth century [during Akbar's time]. The Company was still in an infant stage in the reign of Queen Anne, when on the death of Aurangzib the once mighty Moghul empire was tottering. It was not till the reign of Queen Victoria that the whole of the Indian sub-continent came under the Company's rule. The period from 1704 to 1740 can be said to represent the early adolescence of the East India Company in Bengal. But the economic hold which the Company had established in Bengal foreshadowed for it a promising future. The Fort William Consultations, which flow from 1704 to 1740 without a break, give us a glimpse of the activities of the East India Company and its influence on the economy of Bengal at this formative period. Even in the seventeenth century, the English had found that the farman or charter granted by one Emperor might be disregarded by his successor and that the imperial furman was not always regarded as sacrosanct by the provincial rulers. This naturally gave an element of uncertainty and instability to their position as traders. The uncertain political conditions in eastern India brought home to them the necessity of having a fortified settlement whose permanence and stability could be assured by the possession of estates yielding a steady supply of revenue. Hence the purchase of zamindari rights over the "Calcutta towns" and the construction of Fort William were valued by them because they ensured a regular income and facilitated the movement of their trade. Early in the eighteenth century, the English had realized that, despite the tottering condition of the empire, the name of the great Moghul commanded conĀ· siderable awe and respect all over India. The unhelpful attitude of Nawab Murshid Kuli Khan in Bengal caused them to approach the imperial authorities at Delhi to get a consolidated farman embodying their rights and privHeges. The farman of 1717 conferred on them powers which, in modern parlance, would be regarded as "extra territorial." The fortification of Calcutta and the acquisition of zamindari rights had given them military security and legal status. The farman of 1717 recognised all existing privileges enjoyed by the Company and conferred on them some new ones, which placed them in a superior commercial position over all other merchants, Indian and foreign. It remained the sheet-anchor of the Company's rights in Bengal till the battle of Plassey. The Company had to face powerful opposition in the execution of the provisions of the farman. Both Murshid Kuli Khan and Shuja-ud-din Khan, the Subahdars of Bengal, put obstacles in their way. The exuberance of the Company's servants, on the other hand, led them many a time to exceed its provisions and precipitate awkward situations of conflict with the Government, out of which they could extricate themselves only on payment of heavy fines. The presence of the European rivals of the English -- the Dutch, the French and the Ostenders [Austrians], enabled the Nawab to play off one against the other to his advantage. But ultimately the English emerged triumphant. The Ostend competition, so dreaded by them, was never, in fact, a serious menace. Though there was no love lost between the English East India Company and the Dutch and the French Companies trading in India, the position of the English was certainly strengthened by the prolonged hostility of the French and the Dutch, which was a prominent feature of international politics in the 17th and 18th centuries. Political developments in Europe sometimes compelled the English to conceal their anti-Dutch attitude in India and to remain content to watch their rivals wear each other out. During the war of the League of Augsburg [nine years' war], Pondicberry was captured by the Dutch, but it was restored to the French by the Peace of Ryswick (1697) [also restored Saint-Domingue or Haiti]. The English East India Company had also to cope with the opposition of the banking and trading communities in India led by the house of Jagat Seth. The right of coining money at the Murshidabad mint was denied them by the Nawabs of Bengal mainly at the instance of Jagat Seth, who, as the banker of the Government, regulated the supply of bullion and the coining of money at the mint. The use of the mint by the English Company, which carried on an extensive trade in Bengal, would naturally be detrimental to those having vested interest in the mint. Denied the privilege of coining money at the Murshidabad mint, the English met with no better success in their attempt to secure the circulation of Madras rupees in Bengal according to the terms of the farman. The provision of the farman permitting the circulation of Madras rupees in Bengal would have been an advantage to the English, as they had a mint of their own at Madras where they coined rupees. But here also their interests came into conflict with those of the shroffs, and, particularly, of Jagat Seth, who controlled and regulated the batta or the discount rate for different types of rupees. The batta problem remained unsolved for a long time, even after Plassey. As time passed and the English gained greater stakes in Bengal, they resented more and more the restrictions under which they had to carry on their trade. In their opinion, those restrictions were not justified in terms of the farman. These economic and financial considerations played a large part in moulding their policy for forty years prior to the battle of Plassey and had a decisive influence in the treaties that were made by them with Siraj-ud-daula and Mir Jafar Khan in 1757. The demoralised condition of the rulers was visible to a careful observer as early as 1732, when Anupchand, the vakil of the English at Delhi, drew their attention to the miserable plight of the court, which was 'drowned in luxury', and of the King and nobility whom he branded as cowards. This was revealed on the occasion of the invasion of Nadir Shah in 1739; when the Nawab of Bengal and his advisers made a shameful betrayal of their weakness by their ready acknowledgment of the authority of the conqueror, who was about a thousand miles away from Bengal, and even went on to coin siccas in his name at the Murshidabad mint. The English themselves were extremely nervous at the time of Nadir Shah's invasion. They had realised the inherent weakness of the Bengal Government. By 1740 they felt strong enough to tell the Government that the security of str~tegic points like Patna was dependent on their armed strength. But, as a rule, they avoicded any military conflict with the Government of the day. They followed the advice of the Directors of the Company, who, in their letter of 21 February 1728, recommended the Council of Fort William to maintain friendly relations with the Nawab of Bengal and not to do anything to annoy him; but if at any time the occasion should arise, the Council were advised "to appear resolute to insist upon, defend and preserve their grants and privileges at the cheapest rate possible". Much has been written about the private trade and the abuses of dastaks practised by the Company's servants. In the preceding pages, we have seen that the Company's servants were not the only sinners. The Moghul nobility were no less greedy in this. respect. As the Riyazu-s-salatin tells us, goods purchased in the garb of 'sauda-i-khas' or private trade by high Government officials were sometimes resold to the merchants and passed into the market as 'sauda-i-am' or public transactions on behalf of the Government. The Nawab and the Company differed in their interpretation regarding the nature of the goods covered by the provision of the farman, which gave the Company the right to carry on trade free of customs. The Company's servants, no doubt, very often exceeded the privilege. None the less, it must be admitted that the vigilance of the Nawab and the disciplinary measures taken by the Company kept these abuses under control in the first half of the eighteenth century. Bengal, in the early eighteenth century, enjoyed a prosperous foreign trade. The abundance of her agricultural products and the excellence of her manufactures left little score for the import of articles from outside. The traffic of international trade was, therefore, rather one-sided. The excess of exports over imports had to be paid for by bullion, which flowed into Bengal in increasing quantities as her trade with foreign countries and with Europe grew in volume. "Europe bleedeth to enrich Asia", wrote Sir Thomas Roe, early in the seventeenth century. The truth of this statement was fully illustrated in the first half of the eighteenth century, when Bengal had a continuous excess of exports over imports in the European trade. The mercantile theory of economics, which was then current in Europe, did not favour the idea of the flow of specie out of a country. This explains the anxiety of the East India Company to pay for their Bengal goods by articles manufactured in England, particularly by the woollen products known as broadcloth. But they had little success in their efforts, and the demand for bullion continued throughout the period. Bengal textiles and calicoes had established such a grip on the English market that laws had to be passed by the English Parliament against their importation. These restrictive measures, however, had little adverse effect on industry in Bengal, as the English merchants carried on a lucrative re-export trade to Europe. The industries of Bengal, therefore, held their own in the world market till after the first half of the eighteenth century, when they had to acknowledge defeat before the mechanised system of production evolved in the West. Though we find references to production based on a factory system (for example, the karkhanas) in Moghul India in the works of Indian and foreign writers, the economy of Bengal was essentially based on a system ot almost self-sufficient villages where the cultivator and the weaver pursued their eternal avocation with the little money that filtered into their hands through a number of middle-men who stood between them and the big merchants. Society, which was insular in nature, failed to take notice of the changes which were taking place in other parts of the world. The caste-system with all its rigours operated against the mobility of labour and the progress of society from that of status to contract. There was no dearth of capital in Bengal, though there was little indication ol any capitalistic enterprise. There were indeed fabulously rich bankers, who maintained branches in and outside the province. Their drafts and letters of credit were negotiable even beyond the boundaries of India. But the indigenous banking system was over-dependent on the credit of particular individuals or families, and did not adapt itself to the principle of joint stock that had given so great a stimulus to the contemporary commercial enterprise in England. The economy of Bengal was ill balanced. Wealth was confined to the hands of a small minority lacking in enterprise and impervious to the necessity of developing the potential resources which were present in the country in abundance. A few middle-men clustering round the settlements of foreign traders made fortunes, and the ruling nobility made a show of their wealth at the Court and darbar, but the people, as a whole, were poor, though not so poor in comparison with the people of Europe, as now. There was no enlightened middle class. to form the backbone of a healthy social system. Certain aspects of the activities, or rather the lack of activity, of the people of Bengal may be discussed to show their want of willingness and capacity to recognize facts and to adjust themselves to changing circumstances. The undoubted superiority of European ships, which were far ahead of Indian ships in the quickness of movement and efficiency of transport in carrying foreign and coastal trade, was easily noticeable. Though this was evident ever since the coming of the Europeans, no attempt was made by the Moghul Emperors or by the semi-independent Subahdars of Bengal to build up a navy or to improve their merchant marine so as to match the naval and maritime superiority of the Europeans, which indeed seemed to have been taken for granted. For more than one hundred years before the battle of Plassey, the patrolling of the waters of the Bay of Bengal by the ships of the East India Company and other European powers made no impression on the rulers and people of Bengal... Another feature that strikes a modern student was the lack of scientific approach that characterised the thoughts and activities of the Government and the people. In spite of the vast superiority of the manufactures of Bengal, particularly of textile products, little attempt seems to have been made, while the country had not yet become politically dependent, to import or encourage scientific talents to improve the techniques of production. The English had occasionally to complain against the French, the Dutch, the Swedes, imitating the1r way of producing cettiin articles marketable in Bengal, but never against the Indian manufacturers. Both the Government and the people appeared to be indifferent to the changes that were taking place in the world outside. This spirit of self-satisfaction was fatal to economic progress. No attempt at improving the economy of Bengal on an organised scale by her rulers and people is visible in contemporary records. This atmosphere of complacency brought about a condition of stagnation and contained in truth, the seeds of economic and political decay.
Preface ix I. Introduction : Bengal at the turn of the century 1 II. Trade relations of the English East India Company 10 (I) The Growth of the Company in Bengal (II) The farman of 1717 and Murshid Kuli Khan (III) The working of the farman, 1727 to 1740 III. Other European traders 69 The Portuguese The Dutch The French The Danes The Ostenders IV. Mints and currency 96 The role of the house of Jagat Seth V. Markets and trade 124 Internal and inter-provincial trade Private trade Foreign trade Trade in saltpetre, broad-cloth, etc. silk, cotton goods, VI. General Economic condiitions 168 Conditions of peace Arts and industries Means of communication Standard of life and social contributions of the Company VII. Some Conclusions 210 Appendices 210 I. Subahdars of Bengal, 1700-17-40 218 II. Governors of Bengal Presidency, 1700-1740 219 III. Bibliography 220 IV. Photostat copy of the farman of 1717 226 V. Map of Bengal, 1779 226 VI. Map of the "KASIMBAZAR ISLAND" - 226 Index 227